✅Coupon Code *CYBERWEEK* ✅ https://metkevin.com/join Lifetime access to NEW lectures and access to private livestreams. 🚀🚀LARGEST EVER Coupon!!🚀🚀 STOCKS AND PSYCHOLOGY comes with $5m trading portfolio access!
⚠️⚠️⚠️ #fed #federalreserve #jeromepowell ⚠️⚠️⚠️
Jerome Powell's Brooking's Institute Speech 10:30am today Live on recession and inflation. Jerome Powell speech today. Federal Reserve.
📝Contact Information for Kevin & Liability Disclaimer: http://meetkevin.com/disclaimer
This is not a solicitation or financial advice. See the PPM at https://Househack.com for more on HouseHack.
Videos are not financial advice.

Hey, everyone, welcome back to another speech by Fed chair Jerome Powell He will be speaking uh, well. I Expected to speak in about four and a half minutes. So if you're catching this on replay, you can fast forward probably about four and a half minutes or listen to my preview for the next four and a half minutes. Uh, we've got, uh, drum Pile speaking at the Brookings Institute Uh, he's expected to give a statement and then we're uh, excited for a Q A event afterwards, so not exactly clear how long it'll last. My guess is usually his speeches are less than five minutes long. Uh, and uh, it could be longer. See, Obviously, Usually what happens leading into these uh events is you see, uh, sideways trading in indices or stocks or or sometimes even some, uh, down trading. Uh, so we'll see what happens. Uh, QQQ has been kind of sideways all day long, just jumping up and down. Uh, spy. Let's see, spy. Same thing a little bit of a drop as well. After the Amazon talk about worsening potential recession for next year, That's making a lot of folks nervous that maybe next year is actually going to be worse than a lot of people think it really will be. Uh, you know that that maybe, uh, folks are being too optimistic about, uh, about next year. So we'll see. Uh, it's gonna be very interesting. We've got, uh, some exciting, uh, exciting times ahead, that's for sure. That's one way to look at it. At least that's the optimistic way to look at it. Uh, all right. So again, we're about three minutes away from drum. Pals starting Uh, big things we're going to be looking for: uh, indications, Any indications on the rate hike cycle for December any indications on maybe, uh, an end to the hiking? uh, whether that's May or or when that might be uh and then of course, uh, anything that we can learn about uh, how long do does the FED right now foresee that We might have to keep rates uh at levels before reducing them? Of course. all of these things I Think the FED will kind of Punt on and say we'll have to just see what the data is. So instead I wonder and I think many will wonder. Will the FED tell us anything interesting about how they're seeing the current economy evolve? I Think that those are going to be the most important Clues we're going to look for because anything about speculating about what could happen in the future? I I Don't think is most ideal I Think most ideal is actually seeing what is the Fed seeing right now, understanding what the FED is seeing right now and then maybe being able to trade or invest based off that information based off what the FED is actually seeing. Generally, those I think are the most actionable insights that we get I am expecting, uh, the FED to dial back their regressiveness. So uh, we'll We'll see what happens here. Um, it's gonna be interesting. We're about 90 seconds away from J-pal beginning in the event. uh. launching. We do have uh, feed from the Brookings Institute and uh, we uh, very excited. We'll go ahead and pull this up. Get this going actually. I'll do a quick sound chest. Uh, let's listen into CNBC for a moment, see what they've got to say, right? So this is by Design uh and you know it's going to do damage, but you know it's the kind of damage that sort of has to happen. You know if we're going to get a an economy that slows down to a point where we get inflation back in the box? I'll ask the same question mark I asked a little bit earlier. I mean do you worry that the Federal Reserve can they pull this off? I Mean they're running a balance sheet that's about not quite, but close to twice the size of the annual federal budget of the United States of America and they're going to try to unwind that? I How can they do it? Well, They're not going to try to unwind all of it. You know. Tricky? Very true. No tricky's like I'm gonna try to like walk across this slack rope a foot above the ground on the beach in Venice California That's tricky. This is terrifying. It's doable. It's doable. I I mean uh, the economy is very resilient. I mean the American consumers, you know, uh, got a lot of reasons to keep on spending, not extrapolating. Yeah, borrowing, keep economy moving forward. Businesses here we go. Hold on, let's get this over. here we go. Fellow trustees are here in the audience today. It's my great pleasure to welcome all of you. Uh, both our post pandemic in-person audience here packed house. great to see Uh, as well as our sizable broadcast and online audience. Thank you for joining us today when President Obama named Jay Powell to the Federal Reserve board as Governor in 2012. no one including I suspect Jay expected him to become Fed chair when President Trump named Jay Pal fed uh, as a Gov, the Federal Reserve Chairman in Uh in 2018. Hardly anyone anticipated the global pandemic. And don't forget that then the FED challenge was too little, not too much inflation. So Jay Pal has repeatedly been forced to confront the unexpected and had to steer the United States economy through uncharted waters. He's done it with a steady hand, great personal Integrity Independence and an unwavering commitment to the Fed's Dual mandate price stability and maximum sustainable unemployment. The employment though I don't think I need to explain any of you that today despite stiff headwinds both economic and political. So we're pleased to Welcome to the stage today. um, on behalf of the Brookings institution and the Hutchinson Center on fiscal Monetary policy J Powell Following his remarks Mr Powell field questions from David Wessel the director of Hutchinson Center and from the audience Jay Thank you for joining us and the odd yes that could actually be unexpected. Thank you Glenn It's great to be here today. It's great to be back at Brookings Um, so today, I'm going to offer a progress report on the Fomc's efforts to restore price stability to the U.S economy for the benefit of the American people. Uh-oh And that report must begin by acknowledging the reality that inflation remains far too high. My colleagues and I are acutely aware that high inflation is imposing significant hardship, straining budgets and shrinking what paychecks will buy. This is especially painful for those least able to meet the higher costs of Essentials like food, housing, and transportation shrinking PP Price stability is the responsibility of the Federal Reserve and serves as the Bedrock of our economy without price stability. The economy does not work for anyone in particular. Without price stability, we will not achieve a sustained period of strong labor market conditions that benefit all. We currently estimate that 12-month Pce inflation through October ran at 6.0 percent. While the October inflation data received so far showed a welcome surprise to the downside, these are a single month's data which followed upside surprises over the previous two months. As figure One makes clear, down months in the data have often been followed by renewed increases. It will take substantially more evidence to give comfort that inflation is actually declining. and by any standard, inflation remains far too high For purposes of this discussion: I'll Focus My comments on Core Pce inflation, which omits the food and Energy inflation components which have been lower recently, but can be quite volatile. Our inflation goal is for total inflation, Of course, as food and energy prices matter a great deal for household budgets, but core inflation often gives a more accurate indicator of where overall inflation is heading. 12-month Core Core Pce inflation stands at 5.0 percent in our October estimate, approximately where it stood last. December when policy tightening was in its early stages over 2022. Core Inflation Rose a few tenths above five percent, and it fell a few tenths below. but mainly it moved sideways. So when will inflation come down? I Could answer this question by pointing to the inflation forecasts of private forecasters or of Fomc participants, which broadly show a significant decline over the next year. But forecasts have predict, have forecasts have been predicting just such a decline for more than a year, while inflation has moved stubbornly sideways. The truth is that the path ahead for inflation remains highly uncertain. For now, let's put aside the forecasts and look instead to the macroeconomic conditions we think we need to see to bring inflation down to two percent over time. For starters, we need to raise interest rates to a level that is sufficiently restrictive to return inflation to two percent. There's considerable uncertainty about what rate will be sufficient, although There's no doubt that we've made substantial progress raising our target range for the Federal Funds rate by 375 basis points. Since March as our last post-meeting statement indicates, we anticipate that ongoing increases will be appropriate, it seems to me likely that the ultimate level of rates will need to be somewhat higher than thought at the time of the September meeting. In the summary of economic projections, higher than 4.6 I will return to policy at the end of my comments, but for now, I'll simply say that we have more ground to cover somewhat higher. We're tightening The Stance of policy in order to slow growth in aggregate demand. Slowing demand growth should allow Supply to catch up with demand and restore the balance that will yield stable prices. Over time, restoring that balance is likely to require a sustained period of below Trend growth. Last year, the ongoing reopening of the economy boosted real GDP growth to a very strong 5.7 percent. This year, GDP was roughly flat through the first three quarters, and inequate indicators point to modest growth this quarter, which seems likely to bring the Year in with very modest growth. Overall, several factors contributed to this slowing growth, including the waning effects of reopening and of pandemic physical support, the global implications of Russia's war against Ukraine, and our policy actions which tightened Financial conditions and are affecting economic activity particularly in interest sensitive sectors such as housing. So we can say that demand growth has slowed and we expect that this gross growth will we need will need to remain at a slower pace for a sustained period. Despite the tighter policy and slower growth over the past year, we have not seen clear progress on slowing inflation. To assess what it will take to get inflation down, it's useful to break core inflation into three component categories: Core Goods Inflation Housing Services Inflation and inflation and Core Services Other than Housing Core: Goods Inflation has moved down from very high levels over the course of 2022. While Housing Services Inflation has risen rapidly, inflation in Core Services X Housing has fluctuated but shown no clear trend and I'll discuss each of these items in turn. Early in the pandemic, goodest prices began Rising rapidly as abnormally strong demand was met by pandemic hampered Supply Reports from businesses and many indicators suggest that supply chain issues are now easing. both Fuel and non-fuel import prices have fallen in recent months and indicators of prices paid by manufacturers have moved down. While 12-month core Goods Inflation remains elevated at 4.6 percent, it has fallen nearly three percentage points from earlier this year. It is far too early to declare Goods inflation vanquished, but if current trends continue Goods prices should begin to exert downward pressure on overall inflation in coming months. Housing Services Inflation measures the rise in the price of all rents and the rise in the rental equivalent cost of owner owner-occupied housing. Unlike Goods Inflation Housing Services Inflation has continued to rise and now stands at 7.1 percent over the past 12 months. Housing inflation tends to lag other prices around inflation Turning points, However, because of the slow rate at which the stock of rental leases turns over, the market rate on new leases is a Time layer indicator of where overall housing will go over the next year or so. Measures of 12-month inflation in new leases Rose to nearly 20 percent during the pandemic, but have been falling sharply since about mid-year as figure 3 shows. However, overall Housing Services Inflation has continued to rise as existing leases turn over and jump in price to catch up with a higher level of rents for new leases, and this is likely to continue well into next year. But as long as new lease and inflation keeps falling, we would expect Housing Services inflation to begin falling sometime next year. Indeed, a declining and decline in this kind of inflation underlies most forecasts of declining inflation. Finally, we come to Core Services Other than housing, and this spending category covers a wide range of services from health care and education to haircuts and hospitality, This is the largest of our three categories, constituting more than half the core Pce index. Thus, this may be the most important category for understanding the future evolution of core inflation, because wages make up the largest cost in delivering these. Services The labor market holds the key to understanding inflation. In this category. In the labor market, demand for workers far exceeds the supply of available workers, and nominal wages have been growing at a pace well above what would be consistent with two percent inflation over time. Thus, another condition we're looking for is the restoration of balance between supply and demand in the labor force. The labor Market signs of elevated labor market tightness emerged suddenly in mid-2021. the unemployment rate at the time was much higher than the 3.5 percent that had prevailed. Without major signs of tightness before the pandemic, employment was still Millions below its level on the eve of the pandemic. Looking back, we can see that a significant and persistent labor Supply shortfall opened up during the pandemic. a shortfall that appears unlikely to fully close anytime soon. Comparing the current labor force with the Congressional Budget Office's pre-pandemic forecast of Labor Force growth reveals a current labor force shortfall of roughly three and a half million people. This shortfall reflects both lower than expected population growth and a lower labor force participation rate. Participation dropped sharply at the onset of the pandemic because of many factors including sickness, caregiving, and fear of infection. Many forecasters expected that participation would move back up fairly quickly as the pandemic faded, and for workers in their Prime working years, it mostly has overall participation, however remains well below pre-pandemic trends. Some of the participation Gap reflects workers who are still out of the labor force because they're sick with covet 19. or continue to suffer lingering symptoms from previous covet infections or long covet. But Recent Research by Fed economists finds that the participation Gap is now mostly due to excess retirements. That is, retirements in excess of what would have been expected from population aging Alone, These excess retirements might now account for more than 2 million of the three and a half million person shortfall in the labor force. What explains these excess retirements? So health issues have surely played a role as covet has posed a particularly large threat to the lives and health of the elderly. In addition, many older workers lost their jobs in the early stages of the pandemic when layoffs were historically High The cost of finding new employment may have appeared particularly large for these workers given pandemic related disruptions to the work environment and health concerns. Also, gains in the stock market and Rising house prices in the first two years of the pandemic contributed to an increase in wealth that likely facilitated early retirement for some people. The data so far do not suggest that excess retirements are likely to unwind because of retirees returning to the labor force. Older Workers are still retiring at higher rates, and retirees do not appear to be returning to the labor force in sufficient numbers to meaningfully reduce the total number of excess retirees. So the second Factor contributing to labor to the labor Supply shortfall is slower growth in the working age population. The combination of a Plunge in that immigration and a surge in deaths during the pandemic probably accounts for about one and a half million or missing workers. Policies to support labor Supply are not the domain of the FED. Our tools work principally on demand and without advocating any particular policy. However, I will say that policy to support labor forces participation could over time bring benefits to the workers who join the labor force and support overall economic growth policies would take time to implement and have their effects. For the near term, A moderation of Labor demand growth will be required to restore balance to the labor market. Currently, the unemployment rate is at 3.7 percent near our 50-year lows, and job openings exceed available workers by about 4 million. That is about 1.7 job openings for every person looking for work. So far, we've seen only tentative signs of a moderation in labor demand. With slower GDP growth this year, job gains have stepped down from more than 450 000 per month over the first seven months of the year to about 290 000 per month over the past three months, but this job growth remains far in excess of the pace needed to accommodate population growth over time about a hundred thousand per month. By many estimates, Job openings have now fallen by about a million and a half this year, but remain higher than at any time before the pandemic. That's not great. Wage growth, too, shows only tentative signs of returning to balance. Some measures of wage growth have ticked down recently, but the declines are very modest so far relative to earlier increases, and still leave wage growth well above levels consistent with two percent inflation over time. To be clear, strong wage growth is a good thing, but for wage growth to be sustainable, it needs to be consistent with two percent inflation. So let's then sum up this review of economic conditions that we think we need to see to bring inflation down to two percent growth in economic activity has slowed to well below its longer run Trend and this needs to be sustained. Bottlenecks and goods production are easing and goods price inflation appears to be easing as well, and this too must continue. Housing Services Inflation will probably keep Rising well into next year, but if inflation on new leases continues to fall, we will likely see Housing Services inflation Begin to Fall later next year. Finally, the labor market, which is especially important for inflation in core Services ex-housing again, accounting for more than half of the of the category, shows only tentative signs of rebalancing, and wage growth remains well above levels that would be consistent with two percent inflation over time. So, despite some promising developments, we have a long way to go in restoring price stability. Returning to monetary policy, my Fomc colleagues and I are strongly committed to restoring price stability. After our November meeting, we noted that we anticipated that ongoing rate increases will be appropriate in order to attain a policy stance that is sufficiently restrictive to move inflation down to two percent over time. Monetary policy affects the economy and inflation with uncertain lags, and the full effects of our rapid tightening so far are yet to be felt. Thus, it makes sense to moderate the pace of our rate increases as we approach the level of restraint that will be sufficient to bring inflation down. The time for moderating the pace of rate increases may come as soon as the December meeting. Given our price, our progress in tightening policy, the timing of that moderation is far less significant than the questions of how much further we will need to raise rates to control inflation and the length of time it will be necessary to hold policy at a restrictive level. It is likely that restoring price stability will require holding policy at a restrictive level for some time. History cautions strongly against prematurely loosening policy and I'll close by saying that we will stay the course until the job is done. Thank you! I Just want to say it sounded to me like he explained away almost all the inflation. Okay, they're doing Q a here a little faster. Let's go here. I Want to talk a little bit about Uh. wages and inflation? So uh, as you said, wages are rising faster than it's consistent with a two percent inflation rate assuming reasonable productivity. You said in November that wages are not the principal cause of prices going up, but for many workers, real wages have been falling lately. So I Wonder Isn't there room for wages to rise a bit faster so workers can make up lost ground. And what level of wage increases do you think is consistent with a two percent inflation? Target Okay, so um I guess I Would start by saying that the the inflation that we saw at the beginning of this episode in back in March of 21 was not really related to wages at all. It was related to tightness in in Goods markets, largely due to supply chain issues. Over time though um, inflation is now spread broadly through the economy, and while I would still say that the inflation we're seeing now is not is not principally related to wages, we think that wage increases are probably going to be a very important part of the story going forward, particularly as it relates to that third category of of course Services X Housing. So um, so we think it is an important thing going forward and ultimately in the service sector in particular, where where wages and benefits are are by far the largest cost. um, wages need to go up. And of course, we want wages to go up. We want wages to go up. strongly, but they've got to go up at a level that is consistent with two percent inflation over time, making basic A assumptions about productivity and I would. So if you look at the principal wage measures that we look at I would say that you're one and a half or two percent above that. With with current wage increases so particularly the Employee Employment Common Employee Compensation Index and the Average Hourly Earnings Index, look at those two. It's about one and a half percent higher than what would be consistent, making various adjustments including for productivity from nominal wages. So and as we look at the labor market today, including today's uh, today's Jolts data, what you see is a labor market that there's a really imbalance between supply and demand. There are 1.7 job openings for every unemployed worker. everyone looking for a job, um, the so-called Jobs Workers Gap is about 4 million. Meaning if you if you look at all of the available jobs including people who are working and then look at people who are in the labor force or looking for a job, there's a four million shortfall. So you're in that world and you know we think, uh, that we we there's a job for it for moderating demand in there and getting the labor force back into balance. But you don't think that there's a possibility that we could. We should have a period of catch-up of wage increases above the sustainable level and that businesses with relatively fat profit margins can absorb some of that without passing it through. That that's a, you know, the question of, um, the the worker share of profits and that kind of thing is is not really related to this. Right now, people's wages are being eaten up by inflation. So what you want to do is you want to have inflation stable and then have a very strong labor market where the biggest wage gains are going to the people at the bottom end of the spectrum. And we had that at the end of the very long expansion that ended with a pandemic. That's not what we have now now for most workers. For most workers, the increases they're getting in wages are being eaten up by inflation. That's actually not true at the bottom end where wage increases are are higher than inflation and that's a good thing. But if you want to have sustainable, strong labor market where real wages are going up right across the wage Spectrum especially for people at the lower end, you've got to have price stability. And until we were store that we can't we can't get back to that place where we where we kind of were for the two years before the pandemic hit. And did you take, uh, when you looked at today's Jolts data which measures the vacancies and quit rates, did you find that encouraging? More More or less in line with expectations, But that's going the right direction? That's a good thing, right? Yeah, so yeah, so uh I guess job openings came down by several hundred thousand to to Uh to where they are now. And yeah, that's a positive thing. As you know, the relationship between Uh job openings and unemployment is is a very fraught one, and job openings right now are compared to unemployment are all near their all-time high levels. So it has been our view that there's a possibility that in this highly unusual situation in the labor market, labor market could come back into balance to some extent through a decline in job openings, and that there's been a typical relationship between increasing unemployment and declining job openings, but that our thinking has been, and many labor economists share this, that you could get a decline in job openings that wouldn't produce the same increase in a smaller increase in unemployment than is typically the case looking back in history because of the very outsized level of job openings and we we've kind of seen that so far, but it's way too early to say that that'll that'll So um, traditionally the FED looked at the unemployment rate as a measure of Labor Market tightness and we've seen recently that that may be misleading. Unemployment rate is still very low, and as you pointed out, uh, job vacancies is starting to come down. But to the extent that the FED still relies on a Phillips curve kind of relationship. Um, going forward is the natural rate of unemployment? Uh, useless concept. How will the FED What measures will the FED use to judge labor market slack as we look ahead to policy in the coming years? I Actually I So I think the the way we think about it, of course, the standard way to think about it is it's the gap between the actual unemployment rate and the natural rate of unemployment that matters right? And the issue really. it's not that that framework doesn't make sense, it doesn't make sense. But the the issue is that the natural rate of unemployment is is very hard to identify with certainty, even in normal calm times. But when there's a you know a violent disruption in the labor market, it can move very substantially so. And that happened at the beginning of the of the pandemic you had. The labor market was very much disrupted and we assume that the that the natural rate had moved up meaning that for any level of unemployment, the labor market is tighter. So we knew that and I Think what was different in this cycle was really that you had to look at things like job openings and quits and reservation, wages and just wages overall to tell you that that the natural rate of unemployment had really moved up quite a lot. but I Don't think it's a problem with the framework, but it it's It is A is a fact though, that it's very hard to pin down where the natural rate of unemployment might be. When there's this massive disruption in the labor market going on. Look quickly. He's trying to explain away inflation here. He's talking about. You know these, Concepts about the labor market. But what he's really telling you is, hey, the most important thing is not the unemployment rate going up. it's inflation going down. And he tried explaining that away almost his entire speech. It's kind of interesting. Don't look at it. I've noticed that that's right. I Think I'm just say in this particular situation, we think it's important and we're going to find out empirically whether that was true for the reason. I Reasons: I Explained: We think that we can see a big decline in job openings and less of less than you would expect of an increase in unemployment. So it was. This was a unique in so many different ways. This series of events was different from well, in particular. it's just that so much of the inflation was due to supply side constraints, right? which is not a feature of the US economy for you know for a long time. Well, but uh. Vice Chairman Vice Chair Leo Brainerd said the other day in a speech that she raised the question of whether long-term changes of the economy like labor Supply deglobalization climate change could make the could reduce the elasticity of supply and that this may be a problem going forward. Do you share that? So that's This is a great set of questions that we've all been thinking about a lot and I Lail speech was really terrific on that. Augustine Carson's has given a couple of speeches on the same topic including: One at Jackson Hole this year the head of the Bank for International Settlements Yes, exactly. Uh, so um I Mean the question is, what's is? there's a new normal going to be unlike this normal that we've had where supply side disruptions and constraints were relatively. you could look through them. The the law has been been for a long time that you don't need to worry about that, it'll sort itself out. You know, a supply shock from oil prices or whatever? Are we going into a situation a little bit like the 70s where there will be ongoing repeat shocks and which would tend to have to tend to to put more upward pressure on inflation over time? We don't really know. I Mean that that's a it's a great question, But the question I Guess the real question is what? If that's true, what are the implications? We still have a two percent inflation Target and we still have to use our tools to achieve it and to keep inflation expectations anchored. Um, but it's it's A. It's a very hard to know. It's very hard to know the answers to these things. I Mean we we tend to assume things will go back to the way they were just naturally. uh, but that doesn't seem to be happening so far Right Right now, you mentioned in your remarks that forecasts of inflation have not only those that the Board of Governors but in the private sector as well have been lousy. Okay, inflation has not behaved the way the forecaster said so I Wonder how you think about using forecasts of inflation and making policy if you can't tell us or if your staff can't tell you with with some degree of confidence what inflation is going to be 6, 12, 18, 24 months out? How do you think about that in deciding when you make policy decisions? So I'll say that the Um it is very difficult to forecast inflation now and one of the reasons is just that the situations are the situation is so different from the normal one. and as I mentioned, a lot of it's just that the difficulty is just these supply side constraints that we've had. We had no no experience in forecasting that it was. You know this was a case of first impression. so so that was that was very difficult. Nonetheless, we have. We do make forecasts. We'll continue to make forecasts. Um, what the way I tried to get around that in my remarks was to say let's put the forecast aside for a second and let's try to identify the macroeconomic conditions that we think we need to see that would put downward pressure on inflation. So that's that's a way to think about it. We'll continue to make Um forecasts, but we're going to have to be humble and skeptical about forecasts I think for for some time and that calls for a lot of risk management. Uh, And the other difficulty, of course, is that monetary policy works with long and variable lags. In particular, Inflation is, you know, is at the end of that train and so if you're waiting for actual evidence that inflation is coming down, you know you. It's very difficult not to over tighten if that's if that's all you're doing. So we have a risk management balance to strike, and we think that slowing down at this point is a good way to balance the risks on the pace of rate hikes. I See, kind of just gave away 50 there if you. If you can't use today's inflation rate to set policy and you're not sure what tomorrow's inflation rate is, you're saying the inflation forecasts will be secondary to the economic conditions that you think are likely to generate more or less inflation. Is that basically yeah. First of all, I'm agreeing that it's a very difficult situation in which to forecast deflation and really, very few professional forecasters have gotten it right. So I think we'll look at various things. We'll look at our forecasts. We'll look at the actual data. We'll look at I I gave you the three pieces and the Very and the elements of those three pieces of of core inflation that we're looking at. We will uh, you know, look at these macroeconomic conditions where you know we look at that example. We will try to identify a a level of uh of a stance of policy that's sufficiently restrictive to bring inflation down. We can't identify that with great precision and confidence, but we'll make we'll We'll look at the changes in financial conditions and and the effects that those financial condition changes are having on the real economy. We'll look at all of those things and make a judgment. And it'll have to be judgment as to as to what you know what that is. This is very good. When you think you you've talked frequently about the need to have policy restrictive and that often is used as the definition of restrictive is above some neutral rate of interest, the one that will prevail when all is common. You gave a speech at Jackson Hole a number of years ago pointing out how identifying all these things, the natural rate of unemployment, the natural rate of interest. The problem is that we don't know what they are. So how will you know when policy is restrictive? How do you think about what the neutral rate is under the current conditions of the economy? The answer to that is that there isn't any one Perfect summary statistic. So I The way I Think about it I Think The way we generally think about it is we make our policy changes and they affect financial petitions. Actually, it works the other way around. Financial Conditions Titan and expectation now different from what it used to be. so they tighten it. So we monitor the tightening of financial conditions. We look at at the history of these Financial conditions index and we ask how tight how tight are Financial Conditions We also look at the effect that that tighter Financial positions are having on the real economy particularly now, uh, interest sensitive spending. But also you know other things as conditions tighten, we also look. So what are the financial conditions we look at? We'll we'll look at at the whole the entire rate curve. If you think about risk-free the treasury rate Curve will look to see positive, significantly positive real rates across the curve and you know you have that. You can argue about the short end, but you've got to pick some sort of a forward-leading forward-looking reading for inflation. and I think you know inflation compensation in the markets definitely reflects confidence in us bringing down inflation. So so you've got real rates really across the whole deal curve. You also look though at credit spreads and what are private companies borrowing at Because most part doesn't happen at the Federal Funds rate, it happens in many other places. We look at asset prices. We look at at uh, you know, exchange rates which are just another asset price. We look at all those things and we we try to make a judgment about uh about whether whether looking at put some weight on you know, on the on the real, the real interest rate curve, some weight on the other aspects I Talked about I Think you have to make a judgment at the end though that you're restrictive. So an estimate of the neutral rate of interest didn't seem to be one of the big factors in that list. No, it's in there you you? It's in there in looking at the real rate curve. So you look at the real rate curve you you'd you'd want policy real rates to be above what we'd estimate as the longer run neutral rate. The issue is you know the longer run neutral rate is is a rate uh, at a time of Full Employment and two percent inflation and and the economy and perfect equilibrium that isn't where we are and I noticed um, uh I Turned to the balance sheet. Remember I'm going to turn to questions from the audience in a minute. Uh, how what criteria are you going to use to decide when to end the shrinking of the balance sheet? Is it the economy? Is it? Whether Market money money markets are functioning well? Is it whether the treasury is having trouble raising money? How do you decide when you've shrunk enough when you end this ranking? So I I should refer you to a piece of a document that is that in detail that I really should be reading to you. but I'll paraphrase it. Thank you I Don't get it exactly right. Um, no one, No one will take. Pay attention. If you don't get exactly right, don't worry about it. Relax. So we're in an ample reserves regime, and what that means is that you know changes in the reserve level will generally not affect the federal funds rate. So there's there's more than enough Uh reserves in the system, so we don't. We're not close to reserve scarcity, so what we said is that we would allow reserves to decline until we're somewhat above the level that we think is uh is consistent with an apple. You know, with scarcity, right? And then for a while, what you do is you is you. You hold a balance sheet constant and non-reserve liabilities grow while reserves shrink. So we sort of shrink gradually down to that, and at a certain point we're just going to call it. We're not looking to really go back into proving that they're scarce, because what happens is, and you saw this back a few years. the demand for reserves is not stable and it can move up and down very substantially. So we want to stop at a place that's safe. You know, having a lot of reserves in in the in the system is really a good thing. It's really a public benefit to have plenty of reserves, plenty of liquidity in the markets, and in the banking system in the financial system generally. So that's how well that's how we would do it. Um, in the minutes. Uh, the last Fomc meeting it said this: the staff had a forecast that does not forecast below potential growth, but not a recession. But then there was this interesting 55 sentence where yep, the staff said the possibility that the economy would enter a recession sometime over the next year is almost as likely as their Baseline forecast. just as like is that where you yeah you look at it So I'm I have resisted the temptation to handicap it. uh oh, God I think I'll continue to do that. but um I get the way way I think about it is I I Do continue to believe that there's a path to a soft or softish. Landing I Do believe that. and it's the definition of a softish landing is what. The unemployment goes up a little. but we don't have a recession. Yeah, unemployment goes up, but not it's not. It's not a hard Landing It's not a severe recession. You know, you could think of unemployment going up, but not not. you know, really spiking as it does in some in some uh, recessions. So that's how I think about it. and I think the path is pretty clear. It's we. You know, the labor market. Uh, conditions soften. We see inflation and you know the goods. Inflation gets better. Housing Services Inflation gets better and the labor market softens but doesn't go into recession. Uh, and and you see inflation start to come down and I mean I think that's very plausible I I don't I don't want to be the handicapper on it And you know of course our job is to try to achieve that. and I I think it's still achievable. Although you know if you look at the history, it's not a likely outcome. but I would just say this is a different set of circumstances. So you said at the last press conference that you thought the path to that soft Landing had narrowed, has has it continued to narrow? Or is it widened? or I Don't know if you can have a wide or soft Landing But I I don't know that it's changed since that was this is what five six weeks ago I was asked the question: Has it narrowed? Is it still possible and has it narrow? Is it? It's definitely still possible. And it has narrowed because if you look over the course of this year, nobody expected us to raise rates this much. No one expected inflation to Europe is strong and this persistent and this you know to move to have spread so broadly through the economy and so the extent we need to get keep rates higher or keep them higher longer, That's going to narrow the path to a soft landing. On the other hand, if we get good inflation data and we get evidence that all the things that I talk about if all those things start to swing the other way, then we could very much achieve this. Um, in August 2020, you announced a new framework for monetary policy. the Flexible Average Inflation Targeting Framework. Fate. Uh, and I wonder whether there's anything in that that you think we should be rethinking. Now, in light of the recent experience, he's asking if we should review do another framework review in five years And so that would be to bear fruit in 25 or 26. So that's what we're going to do. We're going to stick to that. I Think we need to see this through a full cycle. We need to see the other side of inflation and what the economy looks like after this historic episode to really make good judgments about that. I will say though, that aside from the framework itself, we implemented it through guidance of various kinds and and you know we were we. We put in really strong guidance because there were a lot of doubters that we would ever achieve two percent inflation. If you remember, that was the main criticism, little did we know. Um, but uh. one piece of guidance that we gave was and I don't I don't think this had anything to do with with or much to do. Let's say it that way. It didn't have much to do with all this inflation we're experiencing. But the one piece of guidance that we gave that I probably wouldn't do again is was we said we wouldn't lift off uh unless until we saw uh both maximum Planet price stability and I don't think I don't think I would do that again because I think it limited it. it's it's uh, the tail risk. You know you. we tend as human beings to underestimate tail risk and I think we didn't We didn't. think it seems so unlikely. If you remember 25 years of low inflation, right? And on many years after the pandemic, after the global financial crisis of inflation everywhere in the world, it's all disinflation, just didn't seem likely. Yeah, and yet here we are. So yeah. So it turns out that when you invite the chairman of the Federal Reserve to speak at Brookings a lot of people email you questions. Most of them are questions I've already asked or questions that were so poorly framed that I couldn't even understand the question. But um, somebody asked me this one and so I want to give that person an opportunity to get an answer. What do you like to do in the morning before you start work? Ride my bike work. No. I get I'm I'm a super early person and I you know I read a bunch of newspapers and drink my coffee in peace and then that's what I do. And now now that you're charity is too, ride your bike to it. Some yeah, some I write down. Well I won't tell you where I write but I do. Yeah right? The security guys thank you for that. No yeah, um okay. so here's the deal. We're gonna take questions from the audience. You need to wait for a microphone to get to you because we have a lot of people online. These could be good. You need to say it should be unpredictable and you need to remember that this is not an opportunity for you to make a speech or tell the FED what it should do. It should be a question. It should be short and questions end with a question mark. So uh, come down here, Want somebody? uh Joe and then Jonathan come on baby. thank you. Uh, trouble you from Brevin Howard So you've spoken both about risk management considerations and the inherent danger of inflation becoming entrenched. So I was wondering what how much do risk management considerations suggest? A terminal rate higher than would normally be expected to achieve your policy goals? So I think there are. There are a number of dimensions and it wouldn't necessarily one of them. One of them would be potentially higher rate, but more I would think um, uh. One risk management technique is to go slower, right to go slower and feel your way a little bit to to what we think is the right level. Another is to is to hold on longer at A at A at a high level and not not uh, you know, loosened policy too early. I Um I I don't want to over tighten. Certainly, we my colleagues and I do not want to over tighten because you know we I think that cutting something we want to do soon. So that's why we're slowing down. Wow, You know I'm going to try to find our way to what that right level is. Theoretically it's another dimension, but it's not. It wouldn't be my first choice. that's totally different from what he said. Last question: Jonathan Pingle with UBS Question about um, the imbalance between labor Supply and labor demand. Um, you know one of the things that's a little obscured when we look at and discuss the labor force participation rate is there is a pronounced downward Trend due to population aging. Um. so when you think about realigning labor Supply and labor demand a or are Fomc officials hoping or expecting um, that participation really moves back up all the way to a pre-coveted peak. And related to that is, you know the follow-on question. You know, how much of the realignment do you think needs to be done through restricting labor demand as opposed to the ability of Supply to catch up. So one labor force participation I think I think it's useful to go back, you know, 10 years And the forecast that that mainstream labor economists had was that you're right aging. aging of the population leads to declining labor force participation. Notwithstanding that Labor First participation was a was in effect flat and a little bit up from 2013 to 2020 roughly and that was because you had a you had a strong, tight labor market, people were staying in the labor market longer than expected. That was really what it was. So our ability to predict is not perfect in this. Except over long periods of time you have an aging population. So you're probably going to have declining labor force participation I Don't think it's reasonable to expect that we get all the way back to where we were with labor force participation in 2020 at 63.7 I guess population adjusted I don't think I don't see that. but I wouldn't rule it out and we're nowhere near that. Now you know we're pointing a half below that now. So um, the real question is, do we expect? Do we expect to see big chunks of Labor Force participation I Gotta say, this year we've seen in the aggregate not much and it's been. it's been very disappointing and a little bit surprising. So um, uh, that's part of the story. The other part, as I mentioned is population Is that the the work, the the labor force, the the part. A big part of the short fall in labor force is actually population as well as participation. So given population Trends Given that there's still some, some workers are clearly anxious about going to work during covet, and given that immigration is well below the levels that were projected before the pandemic, does most of the balancing have to come on the demand side? Well, I think for now, we have to assume that we have to assume that we would. That's why I talked about. you know, supply-side policies on labor, but although they're not for us to recommend or to answer questions about, um, no, didn't please. So yeah, the answer is yeah. I mean that's what I Kind of said that in my speech. we we have to do what it takes to restore balance in the labor market to get back to two percent inflation. Um, and uh, that's what we're doing really, just by slowing growth job growth rather than putting people out of work. This is great. Thank you. Joe Canyon Peterson Institute uh chair Powell Back in 2018, you gave a speech questioning the role of the so-called star variables that the FED uses to navigate and there was a simple possibility raise that maybe unemployment could fall well below what the staff thought the natural right you star was Uh, then without causing inflation. But then Covet came and turned everything around it As you just said, one interpretation of covet is that you star went way up and we were on the wrong side of it. Which is inflationary? My question is going forward: Is it likely? Do you think it's likely that things could reverse as a dust settles from covet and we could end up back in that world where maybe we're on the other side of View Star? We don't know it. It's hard to tell what what lessons did you learn from that period that that got forgotten because of covet? Perhaps well, unemployment went below the low. So what we write down what the staff writes down is a longer run used to our longer run estimate of the natural rate of unemployment. I Guess One thing I would say is that is that during the course of a long, relatively gradual I mean so we only have one experience right to generalize from. But what I learned from that experience was long, relatively slow, not super fast expansion. you really saw the natural rate of unemployment. The shorter term natural rate come way down. We had three and a half percent unemployment with really little sign. Wages were just getting up to that level of productivity and two percent inflation. so we could be back in that place. Um I Think we could certainly be back in that place. I Uh, but what we've what we've seen, you know it's it's another. n equals one situation with with the pandemic. it's also unique. I'd Also point out though we did see the inflation we saw at the beginning, we did have unemployment sorry natural rate of unemployment go up probably significantly. but the again the original inflation we saw was not to do with with the Phillips curve. With the with the labor Phillips curve it was not to do with that, it was to do with Goods more So I Think another way to frame Joe's question is I think a lot of us thought that the lesson we learned when unemployment fell very far and we didn't get inflation that maybe over time before you were in charge. The Fed was aired on the side of being too tight that it was too worried about the unemployment rate falling and I think the concern is that will we fight the last war And because of this experience, the FED will be reluctant to experiment with a low rate of unemployment in the future. I'd Love to have that problem again. If we can get back to it, you know. Okay, so you got like three years left in your term, Do you think you can pull this off in the next few years so we can run the N equals two experiment? Absolutely yeah. Claudia Song hey Claudia song so I'm Consulting So the question I had is we've had unexpectedly fast and large rate increases this year and that has pushed up the dollar relative to basically any currency in the world. We've seen likely more financial market instabilities. So the Federal Reserve School mandate is for the United States And yet are you worried that a severe Global recession or financial Market turmoil would come back to make it harder for us to achieve the U.S dual mandate? So we do. We do of course look at Global developments. we have a domestic Mandate of course as every Central Bank does. But in in this world, uh, Global Financial Markets and the global economy really matter for us. so we we monitor all that very carefully. Um, we really think and my colleagues and I really think that the best thing we can do for ourselves and for the global economy is to get inflation under control as quickly as possible. We don't think the world's going to be a better place if we. If we take our time and and inflation becomes entrenched and then we have to go in later. The the evidence is that the employment costs of uh of bringing inflation down only rise with delay. So um, at the same time we're not. We're We don't want to do any more than we have to do, but we feel like as a risk management uh matter we we need to be. We needed to do what we did and uh and feel like we're now in a place again. As I said, where we can where we can, slow down and and try to reach that that ultimate level. Uh, but how much do you worry about what Claudia's question implies is we do something with rates? Other people are forced to do things with rates and that ends up spilling back to us and makes it harder for you to do it. So you have to take that possibility into consideration. We we absolutely believe that we take that into consideration. The model is explicitly taken into consideration. Of course, they're not perfect. No one can. No one would say we do it. We do it perfectly. But we we I mean we have a very large uh Global model that we use for the global economy and it it absolutely takes into account what hap, what's happening with real, the real economy and monetary tightening and currency and all those things won't be perfect. But we do that and we also sort of understand generally that this that you can. You know there's a lot of research and things talk. People are talking about this a lot right now that you know maybe that the whole is bigger than the sum of the parts when it comes to tightening. Maybe it is. Maybe it isn't, but we're aware of the risk of that. But again, I come back to look where we are. We've we've raised, you know, 375 basis points. Markets are working. Um I Think we're now in a position Where we're We're we're in a place where we really can get inflation under control and we haven't. Unemployment's at 3.7 so we haven't done. I Don't regret getting to where we are And I think broadly, the world will be better off if we can get this over quickly. Thanks Julia Should I stand up so the Mic can find you and this is can I ask uh, um, two questions if they're short? Uh yeah, very short. Um, so one question on the labor market is how do you reconcile? You know the characterization of the labor market is very tight with, um, the fact that wage growth isn't keeping up with inflation in the labor share of GDP really hasn't risen since Uh. 2020.
um and and then second question is how much Credence or what kind of research do you rely on to think about the notion that a very tight labor market will lead firms to invest in and innovate and become more productive over time? I mean what could that be a Tailwind to productivity growth? Okay, I wrote those down really fast now and that was the problem with reading my handwriting. Um, so you asked about um, well, the labor market is tight, but wages are not Rising inflation Okay, and the labor share of GDP which has been depressed right for some time hasn't really started to rise. So how do you put that into your thinking? So um, naturally, we understand that real wages are not going up for most people, but to me, that isn't the the That's true, but it's not really dispositive. I I Think the issue really is that it's one of salience really. So you at what point do people start saying I need higher wages because you know my real wages are going down. You're giving me these six percent wage increases, but inflation is 7.7 I need more of that so we don't really know when that point is. But when you get to that point, you're in serious trouble. and we don't think we're at that point. But it can't be that we can go on for five years at very high levels of inflation and that it doesn't work its way into the wage and price setting process pretty quickly. So that's that's a serious concern. Um, so on on the second question. Uh, yes, no. I Think we're seeing that you know you're you're seeing the service. Industries You're going to see I You know this, this labor shortage that we have. as I mentioned, it doesn't look like it's going away anytime soon and that's absolutely I Think certain to lead to a lot of investment in technology and you know labor replacement technology where there isn't where there isn't labor and you're I Think you'll see quite a bit of that and it could it be a dividend. Uh, going down the road I would think it'll have to be to you know to to provide the services that the public wants to buy. Thanks Mike for early JP Morgan So you spoke about going uh, somewhat restrictive and then staying there for a long time. Why would you prefer that over a shock and all approach that goes very restrictive but for a shorter period of time? And yeah, I asked that because there's some evidence that sacrifice ratios are lower in a more aggressive regime like that. I think we I think we've been pretty aggressive I would say uh no I don't um I I I don't agree I mean we wouldn't you know to just raise rates and try to crash the economy and then and then clean up afterward I I wouldn't I wouldn't take that Approach at all I think we I think we're in a position where the where the right thing to do is to is to move really quickly as we have and now slow down and get to that place where we think we need to be. And by the way, there's High uncertainty around that it. you know we. we have a broad uh set of thoughts about where that destination might be, but we could be wrong. You know it can be higher than that, could even be lower than that we'll have to see. but I think that's the right approach and and that's also the approach that it would. It would allow us not to throw away the option value of of you know, upending a lot of lives which we would do if we if we crash the economy and raise them, we might get rid of inflation. but at very high human cost. There's a question on the very back a woman, uh, in front of the camera. Do you want to stand out? Thanks, Thank you so much for seeing me in the back here. Nancy Marshall Denser from Marketplace Um, just wondering. Cheer Powell Is the Fed in danger of neglecting its maximum employment mandate? Is the maximum employment mandate Taking a back seat to the stable prices or inflation mandate? No, absolutely not absolutely not. we. The the thing is this without stable prices, we can't have maximum employment and that's that's how I think about it. And I think my colleagues as well in the sense that if if you're constantly fighting off inflation and having these battles and having to raise rates and it goes on for five or ten years as it can, you're not going to have maximum deployment. The kind of the situation we would love is to have another one of these very long expansions and we've had four of them now in the last, you know, several decades. Really? When inflation was low after the 70s, we got out of the habit of these short. You know, these short inflation-driven business cycles and we were able to reach you saw where we were three and a half percent unemployment. Those are really good for very beneficial to our society to have these long expansions and the benefits start to go to people at the lower end of the Spectrum in the seventh or eighth year in the last cycle. So I I think the two things go together right now. the labor market is incredibly strong. Again, Before this thing, we've never had 1.7 job openings for every unemployed person. so this is a great Labor Market in in that sense. Uh, it's too great in a way because it's it's going to be adding to inflation. Um, all right. Time for one more on the back. Uh, the gentleman on the aisle. All right. Two questions, Two gentleman on the aisle. keep them short. Thank you. Uh, I'm orange. Uh, orange. welcome South China Morning Post of Hong Kong So I would just like to ask a question related to the Chinese Chinese economy. So uh, right now, a lot of Uh analysts arguing or believe that China's zero Kobe policy is continuing to take a toll on the Chinese economy, but also likely to weigh on the global economy due to the size of China's market and its position in the global supply chain. So we're just wondering about, uh, what impact or how much impact do you accept that uh, continuously slowing Chinese economy would have uh on the U.S economy or the fast next interest rate moves and is China's current economic situation uh, this inflationary factor or uh, inflationary factor to the Us. Thanks again I guess I Just say that the to the extent China is having shutdowns uh in in the parts of the country, in the parts of the economy that are deeply connected to Global Supply chains that is going to make those Supply chains less efficient, less effective and and so that will that will have an effect on you know on on you the prices of some of these Goods that we that are manufactured or assembled in China So it does have an implication for for the U.S It's hard to say how how big that will be uh without knowing how how you know how persistent how how long these lockdowns take place for there's a gentleman behind you. thank you Uh, you're getting shago with public citizen I Was wondering how you think about the trade-off of restrictive policy and the supply constraints you mentioned. So in particularly when it has negative effects say on housing production that makes it harder to meet housing demand or on the Congressional investment through the inflation Reduction act, in climate change mitigation and in energy policy that will make energy cheaper long term. how do you think about that trade-off? Yeah, I Don't think our restrictive policy would have much of an effect on the sort of climate mitigation Investments you're talking about in terms of Uh of housing, you know that there are two things. One, there's a sort of a longer run housing shortage that we have, but in the meantime, uh, we had, uh, coming out of the coming out of the pandemic, rates were very low. People wanted to buy houses, they wanted to get out of the you know, the cities and buy houses in the suburbs because of Covid. And so you really had a housing bubble. You had housing prices going up, but very unsustainable levels and overheating and that kind of thing. So now now the housing. Market's going to go through the other side of that and hopefully come out in a better place between supply and demand. But none of this really affects the longer run issue, which is that we we. You know it's we've got a built up country and it's hard to get zoning. It's hard to get housing built to insufficient quantities to meet the Public's demand. So I Want to thank you chair Powell for being generous of your time and thank you all for coming in. I Want to appreciate everybody asking a question which that's the first time in my experience in eight years in Brookings that's happened I'd like it for all of you to stay in your seats for a minute, uh, until the Chairman can leave safely. And if you have paper at the coffee cups or something, take them to the back of the room and as well as suppose what I'm saying. So thank you very much. Okay, we got to do this. This is. This was so incredible. I Mean this was Huge. Uh, so this is actually right along the lines of what we talked about this morning. Uh, about the potential expectations. So let's do a review on this because this is absolutely freaking phenomenal. Uh uh. this is really good. Oh my gosh. Okay, hold on. let me get the Uh Fed rate. The terminal rate? Uh Federal terminal. Yeah, yeah, it's it's under. It's under. uh, five percent now. Okay, all right, let's talk about this. Hit this really quick. Come on. come on. come on. come on. Uh. And then we're gonna do our summary. All right, Here we go. Wow! We just heard a lot of great news from Jerome Powell and this morning I predicted that Jerome Powell would pull back on the hawkishness and tell us that we're at a level where we can be a bit less aggressive by talking the economy down and talking the stock market down. I Predicted that Jerome Power would relax and kind of back off that incredible hawkishness that he gave us in the last press conference. After that reporter asked a really stupid question saying stocks were rallying when that wasn't even true. and folks I have good news I think Santa Claus is coming to town this year as long as CPI comes in okay on the 13th. I think we got Santa Claus coming and this is exactly what we predicted this morning is exactly what Jerome Powell did. and I'm so impressed with what Jerome Powell said today. and I'm so excited by the discoveries that we have in the big bottom lines that I want to provide you. We have three core discoveries that we just learned from. Jerome Powell Plus, we got a beige book release. This is very, very exciting. Let's start with the beige book release because this is exactly what Jerome Powell had prepared for him before he went into this. Only five of 12 Federal Reserve Districts reported any growth at all and uh, most of them reported flat

By Stock Chat

where the coffee is hot and so is the chat

17 thoughts on “Jerome powell fed speech today recession crisis live”
  1. Avataaar/Circle Created with python_avatars S K says:

    “ and I’ll just sit and grin… The money will roll right in” 🤑

  2. Avataaar/Circle Created with python_avatars AORTA, Inc. says:

    Thanks Kevin!

  3. Avataaar/Circle Created with python_avatars Veronica Davidson says:

    Very interesting sweet pea, but we shall see, love the video boo boo forevermore sweetness sweet pea Pooh Bear guarding her cub alone always my love!🎃🎄🎆🎇✨🎉🎎🎑🎀🎁🎗

  4. Avataaar/Circle Created with python_avatars tactileslut says:

    They're clearly in an alternate reality.
    1) Fed says supply-related pressure on prices is over.
    1a) China doubles down on C-zero, trapping those testing positive away from groceries, work and medical care.
    2) Fed says the lowest earners are coming out ahead of inflation.
    2a) Congress hasn't touched the federal minimum wage but prices for food, goods, services and energy have risen.

  5. Avataaar/Circle Created with python_avatars mjohnstonflying says:

    What a spineless POS. Inflation will come back even stronger. He's folding under pressure.

  6. Avataaar/Circle Created with python_avatars Eventdash01 says:

    The problem is that as soon as Fed eases, the demand will exceed the supply once again. The disaster Biden is still closing down the oil fields that oil companies want and opening up the oil fields that no oil companies can drill for oil. The oil production is only at the level of 2020. And Biden administration is asking other countries to increase oil production instead of increasing domestic production by re-opening the Keystone pipeline etc. Yeah, asking Venezuela who is the worst human rights violator to increase the production of oil. This is awesome. And these countries don't care about the environment. This is the problem with how Americans think. If it doesn't hurt us or our environment, we don't care.

    I thought people saw this, but democrats, liberals and woke still a majority in states like California. The band plays on. Don't think for a second that we are capable of learning the mistakes from the history not to repeat it.

  7. Avataaar/Circle Created with python_avatars kalijuri says:

    In the early 19th century, the forerunner to the Federal Reserve was the Bank of the United States. When Jackson became president in 1829, he vowed to curb the Bank’s power over the national economy, calling the institution “a hydra-headed monster… it impaired the morals of our people, corrupted our statesmen, and threatened our liberty. It bought up members of Congress by the Dozen… and sought to destroy our republican institutions.” Today, many free market economists are saying the same thing about the Fed. PONZI SCHEME.

  8. Avataaar/Circle Created with python_avatars Andrew Mease says:

    lol… I loved the quests asking if workers real wages could be bumped. Not gonna happen, corporations are running the show

  9. Avataaar/Circle Created with python_avatars Dee Kaye says:

    Hmm SHOULD I BUY CAL OPTIONS LIKE FTX KEVVYY BOIII? HMMM SHOULD I????? DO YOU ENDORSE ITTTT???? HMMMMM?!

  10. Avataaar/Circle Created with python_avatars 0 1 says:

    ridiculously optimistic.

  11. Avataaar/Circle Created with python_avatars Travis Berthelot says:

    Sounds like more of the same lies from Powell. More economic manipulation to prop up more unlimited government. We need 2% inflation like we need more of Brandon or Turnip. Those that continue to vote for the 2 Nazi parties in power get what they deserve.

  12. Avataaar/Circle Created with python_avatars Brett B says:

    APE .91 cents 😂

  13. Avataaar/Circle Created with python_avatars starwreck77 says:

    that's a lot of green

  14. Avataaar/Circle Created with python_avatars Paul Moon says:

    So all in on call options and margin

  15. Avataaar/Circle Created with python_avatars Hood says:

    Where was all this talk about price stability when housing prices went up 70% and used cars went up 40-60%

  16. Avataaar/Circle Created with python_avatars Mai Jordan says:

    Thank you !

  17. Avataaar/Circle Created with python_avatars MyContestPix says:

    Kevin is Bullish!! Yay!!!😅🤗🤭🥰

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.